Peterson Institute publications
The Peterson Institute for International Economics is a private, nonprofit, nonpartisan
research institution devoted to the study of international economic policy. More › ›
RSS News Feed Search

News Release

Sanctions Success Is Possible But Not Common

July 15, 2008

Contact:    Gary Clyde Hufbauer    (202) 328-9000
    Jeffrey J. Schott    (202) 328-9000
    Kimberly Ann Elliott    (202) 328-9000

Washington—Economic sanctions have contributed to achieving foreign policy goals in about a third of the cases over the past century, according to a new study by the Peterson Institute for International Economics. Economic Sanctions Reconsidered 3rd edition is a thoroughly revised and updated edition of the Institute's acclaimed and influential work on sanctions by Gary Clyde Hufbauer, Jeffrey J. Schott, Kimberly Ann Elliott and Barbara Oegg. The new edition is based on additional evidence garnered from cases initiated since the 1990s and, in addition to the general analysis of sanctions effectiveness, it analyzes the use of sanctions in the post Cold War era and offers updated policy recommendations for the 21st century.

Economic Sanctions Reconsidered contains comprehensive data and analysis of the use of sanctions over the past one hundred years. The authors examine more than 200 sanctions episodes, including current cases against Iran and North Korea. Key findings include:

  • Sanctions "succeed" in about one-third of the cases overall, but the success rate depends importantly on the type of objectives sought.
  • Success means sanctions contributed significantly to the partial or full achievement of the foreign policy goal.
  • Partial achievement of foreign policy goals is far more common than full achievement.
  • Sanctions are often more effective when aimed against friendly and democratic countries than against adversaries and autocrats.
  • Diversified sanctions—involving a mix of trade and financial measures—succeed more often than cases involving only trade sanctions.
  • Incremental implementation of sanctions (i.e., turning the screw) is less effective than full bore measures. However diplomats prefer to turn the screw.
  • International cooperation doesn't guarantee success but in recent years the record for multilateral sanctions is better than the record for unilateral US sanctions.
  • "Targeted sanctions" are no more successful than traditional measures and those targeting individuals work better as a signaling device than as a coercive measure.
  • Our success rate of one-third overall indicates that in about two-thirds of the cases the foreign policy goal was not achieved or, if it was achieved, other means were decisive (usually military force).

The new edition features an extensive assessment of how sanctions policies have changed since the end of the Cold War. The new political landscape shifted the focus and geographic locus of sanctions, but did not diminish their use. The European Union has become an important sender, particularly in cases involving Africa. Sanctions continue to be deployed frequently and the United States remains the leading practitioner. But the incidence of unilateral actions has fallen as US officials acted in concert with others, and United Nations cases became more prevalent, particularly in dealing with armed conflict within countries (especially in Africa).

Since 1990, sanctions cases also targeted an ever wider spectrum of issues: ethnic strife, civil chaos, human rights and democracy, narcotics trafficking, and terrorism. Sanctions now are often deployed in settings where central government authority is fragile or fragmented; in such cases, sanctions often aim at dissident factions. In addition, new players in the mix, including sub-national governments and nongovernmental organizations, have pushed for new or tightened sanctions against Iran, Libya, Cuba, Burma, and Sudan.


Summary of Findings

Overall, the authors found sanctions to be at least partially successful in 34 percent of the episodes that they documented. However, the success rate importantly depended on the type of policy sought (see table 1). Episodes involving modest and limited goals, such as the release of political prisoners, succeeded half the time. Cases involving attempts to dislodge regimes, to impair a foreign adversary's military potential, or to otherwise change its policies in a major way succeeded less than a third of the time. Efforts to disrupt relatively minor military adventures succeeded in only a fifth of the episodes.

  Table 1 Success by policy goal  
 
 
  Policy goal
Success cases
Failure cases
Total
Success ratio (percent of total)
 
 
 
  Modest policy changes
22
21
43
51
 
  Regime change and
democratization
25
55
80
31
 
  Disruption of military
adventures
4
15
19
21
 
  Military impairment
9
20
29
31
 
  Other major policy changes
10
23
33
30
 
  All cases
70
134
204
34
 
 
 
  Note: This table is based on table 6.1 in Economic Sanctions Reconsidered, 3rd edition.  

The authors find that broad, diversified sanctions have higher success rates on average. Cases in which financial, export, and import sanctions were all deployed succeeded 40 percent of the time, versus 25 percent for trade controls without a financial component. Financial sanctions are more likely to punish the political and military elite in a target country, whereas the pain from trade sanctions is usually distributed across the populace at large.

Such broad and, especially, comprehensive sanctions are blunt instruments. Their economic impact often inflicts collateral damage on the populace at large and sometimes to neighboring countries, while regime leaders and their loyal supporters may escape unscathed. To minimize hardship on the general public and neighboring states, policymakers have tried to design "targeted sanctions"—measures such as arms embargoes, travel bans, asset freezes, and selective banking sanctions—whose impact is focused on specific officials or government agencies. The authors found that the success rate for targeted sanctions is about the same as the success rate for all sanctions. Out of 174 sanctions cases, only 20 cases deployed targeted sanctions outside the framework of comprehensive embargoes. Some 7 of those 20 cases (35 percent) can be judged partially successful.


Recommendations: Economic Sanctions 101

The authors' policy recommendations in past editions remain remarkably robust despite the dramatic changes in world politics and the global economy. Regrettably, their emphasis on the importance of planning to unwind sanctions and restore normal commercial activities has not been faithfully pursued, as evidenced in Haiti, Panama, and Iraq. Some lessons from past experience need to be repeated and others revised to reflect the changing political and economic environment of the 21st century. To that end, the authors offer seven recommendations for sanctions policy:

  • Don't Bite Off More Than You Can Chew. Policymakers (influenced by vocal advocates) often express inflated expectations of what sanctions can accomplish. At most there is a weak correlation between economic deprivation and political willingness to change. The economic impact of sanctions may be pronounced, but other factors often overshadow the impact of sanctions in determining the political outcome.
  • Friends Are More Likely to Comply than Adversaries. Economic sanctions are most effective when aimed against erstwhile friends and close trading partners. These countries have more to lose, diplomatically as well as economically, than countries with which the sender has limited or adversarial relations.
  • Beware Autocratic Regimes. It is hard to bully a bully with economic measures. Senders should not expect that sanctions will work as well against large targets that are strong, stable, hostile, and autocratic.
  • Slam the Hammer, Don't Turn the Screw. There is a better chance to avoid military escalation if sanctions are deployed with maximum impact.
  • More Is Not Necessarily Merrier. A large coalition of sender countries does not necessarily make a sanctions episode more likely to succeed. Cooperation is generally sought only when the objective is very ambitious and is often not needed when goals are more modest. Moreover, the greater the number of countries needed to implement sanctions and the longer the sanctions run, the greater the difficulty of sustaining an effective coalition.
  • Choose the Right Tool for the Job. Sanctions often are the first course in a menu of actions against belligerent nations. In many instances, they are deployed in conjunction with other measures directed against the target: covert action or military operations. In some cases, economic sanctions merely provide an interim response until military action can be organized—as President George H.W. Bush admitted in his memoirs about the first Gulf War.
  • Don't Be a Cheapskate or a Spendthrift. Senders need to match costs imposed on domestic constituencies (and allies) to expected benefits; otherwise, public support for the sanctions policy may quickly erode. But senders also need to take care not to worry so much about minimizing self-inflicted costs that they devalue the impact of the overall exercise.

Although economic sanctions may be the best or even the only option in cases where it is politically necessary to "do something," not just any sanction will do. The sanction chosen should be appropriate to the circumstances and leaders should carefully analyze the unintended costs and consequences before selecting a particular measure. Senders usually have multiple goals in mind when they impose sanctions, and coercion is not always at the top of the list. Equally important, prudent leaders should consider, in advance, how they or their successors will discard or refashion the old suit when it no longer serves its original purpose.


About the Authors

Gary Clyde Hufbauer resumed his position as Reginald Jones Senior Fellow in 1998. Previously he was the Marcus Wallenberg Professor of International Financial Diplomacy at Georgetown University and served in the US Treasury Department from 1974 to1980. Dr. Hufbauer holds an AB from Harvard College, a PhD in economics from King's College at Cambridge University, and a JD from Georgetown University Law Center. His coauthored publications include US Taxation of Foreign Income (2007), US-China Trade Disputes: Rising Tide, Rising Stakes (2006), and NAFTA Revisited: Achievements and Challenges (2005).

Jeffrey J. Schott, senior fellow, joined the Peterson Institute in 1983. During his tenure at the Institute, he was also a visiting lecturer at Princeton University (1994) and an adjunct professor at Georgetown University (1986–88). He was a senior associate at the Carnegie Endowment for International Peace (1982–83) and an official of the US Treasury Department (1974–82) in international trade and energy policy. His publications include NAFTA Revisited: Achievements and Challenges (2005), Free Trade Agreements: US Strategies and Priorities (2004), and Prospects for Free Trade in the Americas (2001).

Kimberly Ann Elliott is a senior fellow jointly at the Peterson Institute and the Center for Global Development. She has been associated with the Institute since 1982. Her publications include Delivering on Doha: Farm Trade and the Poor (2006), Can Labor Standards Improve Under Globalization? (2003), Corruption and the Global Economy (1997), and Reciprocity and Retaliation in US Trade Policy (1994).

Barbara Oegg is a consultant to the Peterson Institute for International Economics. She was a research associate at the Institute from 1998 to 2004. She has coauthored numerous articles on economic sanctions, including "The Impact of Economic Sanctions on US Trade: Andrew Rose's Gravity Model" (2003), "Capital-Market Access: New Frontier in the Sanctions Debate"(2002), and "Using Sanctions to Fight Terrorism" (2001).


About the Peterson Institute

The Peterson Institute for International Economics, directed by C. Fred Bergsten since its inception, is the only major research center in the United States that is primarily devoted to global economic policy issues. Founded in 1981, its staff includes more than two dozen experts who focus on macroeconomic topics, international finance and exchange rates, trade and related social issues, energy, the environment, global investment, and domestic adjustment measures. Its expertise covers all key regions of the global economy—especially Asia, Europe, and Latin America. The Institute is private and nonprofit, it is one of the only think tanks widely regarded as nonpartisan by both the press and Congress, and its scholars are cited by the quality media more than any other such institution. Support is provided by a wide range of charitable foundations, private corporations, individual donors, and from earnings on the Institute's publications and capital fund. It celebrated its 25th anniversary in 2006 and adopted its new name at that time, having previously been the Institute for International Economics.

Economic Sanctions Reconsidered, 3rd edition
by Gary Clyde Hufbauer, Jeffrey J. Schott, Kimberly Ann Elliott, and Barbara Oegg

ISBN Hardcover + CD-ROM 978-0-88132-408-2
May 2008 • 233 pp. • $49.95

ISBN Hardcover 978-0-88132-407-5
November 2007 • 233 pp. • $36.95
The CD-ROM is not sold separately.

Download news release as pdf